Read the following passages carefully and answer the questions given at the end of each passage:
Every loan has a lender and a borrower; both voluntarily engage in
the transaction. If the loan goes bad, there is at least a prima facie
case that the lender is as guilty as the borrower. In fact, since
lenders are supposed to be sophisticated in risk analysis and in making
judgments about a reasonable debt burden, they should perhaps bear even
more culpability.
Does it make a difference if we say there is
over-lending rather than over-borrowing? The difference in where we see
the problem affects where we seek the solution. Is the problem more on
the side of the lenders, that they are not exercising due diligence in
judging who is creditworthy? Or on the borrowers, being profligate and
irresponsible? If we consider the problem to be over borrowing, then we
naturally think of making it more difficult for borrowers
to
discharge their debts, on the contrary, if the problem is over lending,
we focus on strengthening incentives for lenders to exercise due
diligence.
The political economy of over-borrowing is easy to
understand. The current borrowing
government benefits and later
governments have to deal with the consequences. But why have
sophisticated, profit maximizing lenders so often over-lent? Lenders
encourage indebtedness because it is profitable. Developing country
governments are sometimes even pressured to over-borrow. There may be
kickbacks in loans, or even to be influenced by Western businessmen and
financiers. They wine and dine those responsible for borrowing as they
sell their loan packages, and tell them why this is good time to borrow,
why their particular package is attractive, why this is the right time
to restructure debt? Countries that are not sure that borrowing is worth
the risk are told how important it is to establish a credit rating:
borrow even if you really don’t need the money.
Excessive borrowing increases the chance of a crisis, and the cost of a crisis are borne not just by lenders but by all of society. In recent years, IMF programs may have resulted in significant further distortions in lenders’ incentives. When crisis occurred, the IMF lent money in what was called a ‘bail-out’- but the money was not really a bail-out for the country; it was a bail out for western banks. In both East Asia and Latin America, bail-outs provided money to repay foreign creditors, thus absolving creditors from having to bear the costs of their mistaken lending. In some instances, governments even assumed private liabilities, effectively socializing private risk. The creditors were left off the hook, but the IMF’s money wasn’t gift, just another loan- and the developing country was left to pay the bill. In effect, the poor country’s taxpayers paid for rich country’s lending mistakes.
The
bail-outs give rise to the famous ‘moral hazard’ problem. Moral hazard
arises when a party does not bear all the risks associated with his
action and as a result does not do everything he can to avoid risk. The
term originates in the insurance literature; it was deemed immoral for
an individual to take less care in preventing a fire simply because he
had insurance coverage. It is of course, simply a matter of incentives:
those with insurance may not set their houses on fire deliberately, but
their incentive to avoid a fire is still weakened. With loans, the risk
is default, with all of its consequences; lenders can reduce that risk
simply by lending less. If they perceive
a high likelihood of a
bail-out, they lend more than they otherwise would.
Lending markets are also characterized by, in the famous words of former chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Alan Greenspan, ‘irrational exuberance’, as well as irrational pessimism. Lenders rush into a market in a mood of optimism, and rush out when the mood changes. Markets move in fads and fashions, and it is hard to resist joining the latest fad. If only one firm were affected by a mood of irrational optimism, it would have to bear the cost of its mistake; but when large numbers share the mood, in a fad, there are macroeconomic consequences, potentially affecting everyone in the country.
From the last line of fourth paragraph, it can be inferred that the author believes that the cost of the crisis is ultimately borne by the tax payers of the borrowing country. Therefore, the answer is option C.
Create a FREE account and get: